Steve Pearson is quoted in today's New York Times as filling in the evidence gap prostate cancer care... Wow.
“Most policy makers think that, in general, we would want to do more national coverage decisions, partly because there’s a concern that the evidence review in most local regions isn’t very good,” said Dr. Steven D. Pearson. He is president of the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review, an organization partly financed by the insurance industry that is pushing for the use of evidence in medical decisions.
But that concern reflects an impatience with the views of others, particularly patients and physicians who would disagree with comparative effectiveness decisions that Pearson and his group would be entitled to produce under proposed comparative effectiveness legislation. His response to to a piece by Tom Philipson in health affairs about how comparative effectiveness analysis is, in fact, price controls is revealing:
"Surely an innovation that creates a near-cure for HIV should be valued more than a new combination pill of previously established drugs. It seems nonsensical that society would want to lavish rewards on innovators who produce equivocal or marginal gains and charge a steep price. The key is not to control prices but to incentivize investment in interventions that yield significant gains in effectiveness. When used rigorously and transparently, cost-effec-tiveness criteria can send the signal that the bestway to succeed as an innovator is to create interventions that are much more effective than previous alternatives. This is the signal that is missing from much of the U.S. healthcare system, where low-risk and marginally superior interventions are marketed to price insensitive physicians and patients.
I would completely reframe the authors’ argument by advocating that linking insurance coverage to cost-effectiveness might make patients feel a little worse off today but would
greatly benefit future patientswho will inherit a less bloated and wasteful health care system. That way, future patients will find a health care market dominated by focused, skilled innovators
who know that their greatest reward will come from producing interventions of greatly enhanced effectiveness at a reasonable cost. If, as a result, some of today’s venture capital chooses to flee elsewhere to seek easier returns, so be it. Let’s get the innovation we want."
Note how he concludes that government set criteria or criteria provided by the institute via government contracts can replace "price insensitive physicians and patients." Then and only then my friends will be the innovation "we" want. And if we make patients a little worse off in the process, oh well.
“Most policy makers think that, in general, we would want to do more national coverage decisions, partly because there’s a concern that the evidence review in most local regions isn’t very good,” said Dr. Steven D. Pearson. He is president of the Institute for Clinical and Economic Review, an organization partly financed by the insurance industry that is pushing for the use of evidence in medical decisions.
But that concern reflects an impatience with the views of others, particularly patients and physicians who would disagree with comparative effectiveness decisions that Pearson and his group would be entitled to produce under proposed comparative effectiveness legislation. His response to to a piece by Tom Philipson in health affairs about how comparative effectiveness analysis is, in fact, price controls is revealing:
"Surely an innovation that creates a near-cure for HIV should be valued more than a new combination pill of previously established drugs. It seems nonsensical that society would want to lavish rewards on innovators who produce equivocal or marginal gains and charge a steep price. The key is not to control prices but to incentivize investment in interventions that yield significant gains in effectiveness. When used rigorously and transparently, cost-effec-tiveness criteria can send the signal that the bestway to succeed as an innovator is to create interventions that are much more effective than previous alternatives. This is the signal that is missing from much of the U.S. healthcare system, where low-risk and marginally superior interventions are marketed to price insensitive physicians and patients.
I would completely reframe the authors’ argument by advocating that linking insurance coverage to cost-effectiveness might make patients feel a little worse off today but would
greatly benefit future patientswho will inherit a less bloated and wasteful health care system. That way, future patients will find a health care market dominated by focused, skilled innovators
who know that their greatest reward will come from producing interventions of greatly enhanced effectiveness at a reasonable cost. If, as a result, some of today’s venture capital chooses to flee elsewhere to seek easier returns, so be it. Let’s get the innovation we want."
Note how he concludes that government set criteria or criteria provided by the institute via government contracts can replace "price insensitive physicians and patients." Then and only then my friends will be the innovation "we" want. And if we make patients a little worse off in the process, oh well.