Latest Drugwonks' Blog
The Healthy Indiana Program was established by Governor Mitch Daniels to provide affordable and comprehensive health insurance to lower income Hoosiers. Using a combination of tobacco taxes and Medicaid dollars, it serves more than 42,000 Hoosiers. The plan requires enrollees to contribute up to 5% of their gross income to a POWER account, which is used to pay for medical expenses. The state covers the balance needed to raise the account to $1,100. People who use preventive services get a reduced premium and get to carry over a portion of the POWER account from one year to the next. The average premium is $130
Unfortunately, Governor Daniels had to freeze HIP enrollment in March 2010 because under Obamacare HIP enrollees will have to go into Medicaid.
Health and Human Services Secretary Kathleen Sebelius told an audience at the Indiana University School of Medicine on May 14, 2010 that the health reform law didn't outlaw Healthy Indiana. "There's no change that [health reform] made that would make this waiver program difficult to pursue in the future."
PS The federal waiver authorizing Healthy Indiana expires at the end of 2012.
PPS In November of 2011, Sebelius rejected Indiana’s request to keep Healthy Indiana and exempt it from Obamacare.
About 25,000 adults without children have been on a waiting list for the program, while adults with kids are still being enrolled.
Unless Obamacare is overturned or dramatically reformed, they will still be waiting. Their only choice will be Medicaid. As the video on Healthy Indiana shows, for those who rely on HIP for coverage, that’s not a choice at all.
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=qoWothG4b2Y
Too often media coverage of scientific studies are rife with what behavioral economist Daniel Kahenman calls "the availability heuristic." The availability heuristic is a mental shortcut that uses the ease with which examples come to mind to make judgements about the probability of events.
In reporting terms that translates into taking top line results and fitting into a pre-conception or narrative.
Such is the case with reporting on a study comparing the effectiveness of paclitaxel and bevacizumab with a nano-sized form of paclitaxel called Abraxane & Avastin as well as Xyempra and Avastin.
Here's the MedPage account of the study:
"Patients with metastatic breast cancer did just as well -- and maybe better -- with paclitaxel-based chemotherapy compared with two newer, more expensive agents, results of a randomized trial showed.
First-line treatment with weekly paclitaxel and bevacizumab (Avastin) resulted in a median progression-free survival (PFS) of 10.6 months compared with 9.2 months with nanoparticle albumin-bound paclitaxel (nab-paclitaxel or Abraxane) and 7.6 months with ixabepilone (Ixempra), each paired with bevacizumab.
The ixabepilone arm had significantly worse PFS at an interim analysis and was dropped from the trial.
Patients who received paclitaxel also had less peripheral neuropathy than with either of the other drugs, and less hematologic toxicity than those who received nab-paclitaxel, Hope Rugo, MD, reported here at the American Society of Clinical Oncology meeting.
"Neither weekly nab-paclitaxel nor ixabepilone is superior to weekly paclitaxel," Rugo, of the University of California San Francisco, said during an ASCO press briefing. "Weekly paclitaxel appears to offer better progression-free survival than ixabepilone."
"These data suggest that similar patients could be appropriately treated with weekly paclitaxel," she added.
During the discussion that followed her presentation, Rugo described cost issues surrounding cancer therapies as "enormously complicated," but said that generic drugs such as paclitaxel will always be less expensive than newer drugs that are not available as generics.
Funded by the National Cancer Institute (NCI), the trial came about as a result of recent developments in the treatment of metastatic breast cancer."
Of course, the funding had nothing to do with comparative effectiveness research efforts to claim that cheaper is better. But I digress
The study and the Medpage article is yet more evidence -- pouring in at the ASCO meeting as I write -- that targeted therapies or targeted use of therapies based on biomarkers and mechanisms of action implicated in both toxicity and tumor response -- is replacing the one size fits all approaches and comparisions that NCI supports.
The fact that you have to get into the weeds about the study and have to put it into context of other studies looking at Abraxane and Xyempra underscores this point.
For instance: Abraxane was designed to be longer lasting and administered at lower doses and less often.
The study used 150 mg/m2 weekly and has a 30% higher weekly dose intensity than the approved dose of 260 mg/m2 every 3 weeks.
Still Abraxane has been used in weekly fashion, to great effect: "in phase 2, median progression-free survival (PFS) was 18.9 months for 150 mg/m2 weekly nab-paclitaxel vs 8.5-13.8 months for all other regimens. In phase 3, median PFS for q3w nab-paclitaxel and solvent-based paclitaxel were 5.6 months and 3.5 months, respectively. Weekly nab-paclitaxel resulted in less serious adverse events compared with all other regimens.
Breast. 2011 Oct;20(5):468-74.
The outlier in all Abraxane studies is the current one. Why? Abraxane is formulated as a monotherapy for metastatic breast cancer, not in combination with Avastin. It's not just a stronger or smaller form of paclixtel.. it also targets a previously unrecognized tumor upregulated path through the blood vessel wall.
Nearly half of the people enrolled in the study dropped out due to toxicity issues. So in effect, the investigators forced cancer patients to stay on a regimen that was toxic..
Yet, even using Abraxane in an off-label manner, patients who took the combo lived an average (again, a suspect number in cancer trials these days) of 9.6 more months compared to 10.4 months for paclixtel and Avastin.
Did the higher toxicity result from the combination of a higher than prescribed dose and using it with Avastin? They researchers and the media account don't even ask that question. Instead they hew to the availability heuristic:
Rugo described cost issues surrounding cancer therapies as "enormously complicated," but said that generic drugs such as paclitaxel will always be less expensive than newer drugs that are not available as generics.
Well, yes they are. For instance:
1. One smaller dose of Abraxane costs slightly more than the same as four weeks of paclitaxel.
2. Several studies have shown that Abraxane use in women with MBC cuts down on the amount of time and services required to treat toxicity, to administer the drug and enhances quality of life. For isntance: " Nab-paclitaxel had the lowest incidence of grade III/IV toxicity. This translated to lower overall costs for managing the grade III/IV events relative to both docetaxel and paclitaxel ($597 vs. $2626 vs. $1227). Using the median number of cycles administered and the cost impact of grade III/ IV toxicity, the overall cost for nab-paclitaxel would be $15,105 compared to $15,268 for docetaxel and $3557 for paclitaxel. When treatment preferences were assessed, 20 of 24 (83.3%) respondents selected nab-paclitaxel as their preferred choice compared to only 4 who selected docetaxel." J Oncol Pharm Pract. 2009 Jun;15(2):67-78.
3. Then there's the fact that there are severe shortages of paclitaxel:
Chemo Drug Taxol Shortage Puts Cancer Patients at Risk
So is it worth switching breast cancer patients to a drug that incurs more costs and reduces quality of life, a drug that people die waiting for?
No one asked or answered that question.
CBO Estimate of the Statutory Pay-As-You-Go Effects for an Amendment in the Nature of a Substitute to H.R. 5651, the Food and Drug Administration Reform Act of 2012, as posted on the Web site of the Committee on Energy and Commerce on May 25, 2012
Source: Congressional Budget Office.
The bill would modify how the Food and Drug Administration regulates drugs and devices in a broad range of areas. Several provisions of the bill would affect when lower-priced drugs enter the market. Changing the timing of availability of lower-priced drugs affects spending in federal health programs that pay for prescription drugs and biological products. It would also affect the costs of health insurance plans and thus federal subsidies for health insurance purchased through an exchange. On net, the bill would result in a reduction in the deficit of $114 million over the 2012-2017 period, which is the sum of a reduction in direct spending of $113 million and an increase in revenues of $1 million. Similarly, the 10-year net reduction in deficits of $370 million is the sum of a reduction in direct spending of $365 million and an increase in revenues of $5 million.
The CBO chart can be found here.
The mayor will issue a proclamation in honor of the day established by the Salvation Army in 1938 to honor donut lassies who served treats to soldiers in WWI.
Mayor Bloomberg has stirred up controversy by saying he wants to ban the sale of sugary drinks over 16 ounces from establishments that receive a letter grade from the Health Department.
The health commissioner says the ban could make an immediate impact.
"Sugary drinks are not the entire obesity epidemic but they are uniquely strongly associated with the rise in obesity over the last 30 years. There's something about this sugar water product which leads to long term weight gain," said City Health Commissioner Thomas Farley.
The New York City Beverage Association and fast food restaurants are among those sharply criticizing the plan, with a spokesperson for McDonald's calling it "misguided."
The Riverdale Press
May 30, 2012
By Peter J. Pitts
The second anniversary of President Obama’s Affordable Care Act (ACA) just passed. And two years after its enactment, the debate over health care reform is every bit as contentious. The recently released forecast from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) offers fodder to both sides.
On one hand, the law may cost $50 billion less over the next ten years than projected in January — but the national budget deficit is now projected to be $93 billion higher. Medicare and Medicaid expenditures are projected to more than double over the next decade, despite 4 million fewer Americans getting health insurance.
For anyone in favor of improving our healthcare system, these numbers make clear just how desperately our county’s entitlement programs need real reform.
Unfortunately, the president’s chosen cost-cutting strategy for Medicare — the establishment of the Independent Payment Advisory Board (IPAB), an all-powerful panel of budget enforcers — is one of the most harmful aspects of ACA. Lawmakers must cast this flawed approach to reform aside and focus instead on innovative initiatives that address the program’s real cost-drivers while protecting seniors’ access to care.
IPAB is a board of 15 presidential appointees. Unelected and unaccountable, these bureaucrats are tasked with drawing up budget cuts if Medicare expenditures exceed preset targets.
Those targets will almost certainly be surpassed. Medicare spending is expected to be $575.7 billion this year, jumping to over $1 trillion by 2022, as the country ages. Over the next 75 years, the program is projected to accumulate a $38 trillion budget shortfall.
Much of this enormous price tag goes towards financing Medicare Parts A and B. And yet, IPAB has no authority over either. In fact, the board can’t make any substantive structural changes. Neither the fee-for-service structure nor enrollee premiums and fees can be altered.
The board’s only viable option is to further ratchet down reimbursement rates for Medicare providers, especially doctors, who are already losing money on Medicare patients. Indeed, the financial burden of too-low payments under Medicare has driven 17 percent of doctors and 31 percent of primary care physicians across the country out of the Medicare program altogether, according to a study from the American Medical Association.
If rates fall any lower, seniors will have an increasingly difficult time securing doctor appointments. Visits will be cut short to squeeze in patients and care compromised.
IPAB is even more insidious because it deflects policymakers’ attention from innovative reform efforts with real cost-saving potential.
Last June, the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) launched two such initiatives.
The first would make $42 million available to improve coordination of care for Medicare enrollees. Consider that just about half of Medicare beneficiaries suffering from congestive heart failure are readmitted to a hospital within six months of discharge. Each readmission costs an average of $7,000. The health and monetary benefits of improved coordination to make such readmissions unnecessary would be huge. Evidence shows that well designed transitional care between providers can dramatically reduce costs and improve health care outcomes.
Limiting preventable Medicare hospital readmissions could save nearly $245 billion over the current ten-year budget window, according to MedPAC. Even a 40 percent reduction could save $100 billion over that same period.
The second HHS initiative combats chronic illness. This has enormous cost-cutting potential, as 75 percent of health care expenditures go towards the treatment of chronic diseases. Diabetes, heart disease and strokes alone cost $1 trillion annually.
Patient coaching and health education could both improve enrollee health and reduce the costs of treating such illnesses. A clinical trial of the Diabetes Prevention Program found that enrolling overweight adults aged 60-64 in a community-based weight loss program could save Medicare between $1.8 and $2.3 billion over ten years.
Both HHS initiatives hold the promise of saving money and lives. The same cannot be said for IPAB. Instead of generating savings by improving the health of beneficiaries, IPAB devalues these efforts, squeezing doctors and providers to the detriment of seniors.
It’s time to support a Medicare cost-saving strategy that encourages long-term strategic thinking. Congress must repeal IPAB and stand up for real Medicare reform.
Peter Pitts is President of the Center for Medicine in the Public Interest and a former FDA Associate Commissioner.
“The health department/City Hall will tomorrow propose that any location that gets a restaurant letter grade will be barred from selling sugar-sweetened beverages over 16 ounces. This would also apply to food trucks.”
And here’s something from the NYC Fox affiliate:
“Get ready to sell smaller containers of soda and other sweetened drinks. The obesity task force with the New York City Department of Health is ready to recommend that containers for sweetened beverages be limited to 16 ounces. The rule would affect drinks sold at delis, fast-food franchises, sports arenas, and sidewalk carts. Anyone who violates the regulation would be fined $200 for every sale.”
I can’t wait for the first 7-11 sting to stop the sale of Big Gulps, the undercover operation to the illegal sale of Mountain Dew refills at movie theaters and the Gatorade bodega/salad bar busts designed to break up multiple bottle sales.
It would also apply to those souvenir soft drink cups at Yankee Stadium, CitiField and Madison Square Garden. But not the 24 ounce beer cups. (As we all know, beer does NOT add weight.)
Or jumbo sno-cones. (I think.) Or coffee with lots of sugar and cream. Then again, will we be allowed to add sugar to our beverages?
I am sure some people actually care if such a regulation will – as Bloomberg claims – reduce obesity. It really doesn’t matter. If obesity rates (using the unreliable measure of Body Mass Index) remain essentially unchanged in The Big Apple(and the have not really budged since 2005 ) since the Mayor started his crack down on sugar and soft drinks ( the consumption of the latter also remains essentially flat) then it will be argued that the assault on serving size is critical.
If Bloomberg claims (incorrectly) – as he has– that the subway ads linking soft drinks to morbid obesity and a ban on soda sales in schools have reduced obesity (and they have not) then a container size crackdown will lead to even greater gains, I mean losses. In fact, sweetened beverage consumption has declined nationwide over the past few years. Do we really know why? No. Does it have any affect on health? No one knows. Are NYC statistics on sweetend-beverage consumption reliable. The data is based on self-reported consumption. For all we know, all the kvetching about soft drinks is just making people lie.. as in telling those conducting surveys what they think they want to know. But who cares? And who in the media has ever looked at the data apart from using it to restate the narrative of evil corporations poisoning our kids. So much for the media being more careful reporting statistics and science after perpetuating the Wakefield vaccine fakery.
We have arrived at this silly place in public policy because the operators of the Nanny State and the media willingly accept the spurious correlation between soda consumption and obesity because it reaffirms pre-existing biases. These biases are reinforced by sloppy “studies” that associate watching TV with drinking soft drinks and both with obesity. Next thing you know NYC is running ads linking soda to leg amputation.
Nagging – by our parents or a billionaire baby sitter with too much time – and one term too many – on his hands has never produced changes in habits, especially eating, drinking and exercise. People – especially in NYC – will find a way to chow and slurp down what they want, when they want.
Which they will. After they stop laughing and ridiculing the latest Bloomberg effort.
The U.S. House of Representatives voted 387-5 on Wednesday to pass its version of PDUFA reauthorization legislation. The bill will now need to be reconciled with a version that passed the Senate last Thursday. Majority Leader Eric Cantor said he hopes to reach an agreement with the Senate by July 4 on a final bill to send to President Obama.
You need to show a decline in rates of death in a randomized clinical trial conducted over ten years in mostly white Europeans
The decline in death rates has to be from all causes, not the disease you were screening for
The determination of what a sufficient decline in death rates is at the sole discretion of USPSTF.
In otherwords, no new screenings such as this new breast cancer detection tool being developed in Israel.
A game-changer in breast cancer detection
Early detection is the key to improving breast cancer survival rates, but mammography is not the ideal method to accomplish this goal. On this point, medical experts across the globe agree.
Not as clear is what could do the job without the disadvantages of mammography — which often causes pain or discomfort; emits radiation; cannot properly image dense breast tissue; relies on a radiologist’s interpretation of the image; and is not recommended for routine screening of women under age 40 or 50.
Of several approaches being developed worldwide, an Israeli solution pioneered by electro-optical engineer Boaz Arnon holds particular promise in providing a game-changing device for early detection of breast cancer.
Arnon’s mother, Ruth, succumbed to the disease in 2004. Through Real Imaging, the company he founded in 2006, he was determined to offer an accurate alternative that would address all issues of concern and still be cost-effective.
Appropriately named RUTH, the device he invented uses a new trademarked platform he calls MIRA (functional Multidimensional Infra-Red Analysis). Built on principles from existing technologies and mathematics, MIRA enables functional quantitative analysis of 3D and infrared signals emitted from cancerous and benign breast tissue.
“Our solution is not sensitive to age or breast density, and works without radiation,” Arnon tells ISRAEL21c. “We image the patient from a distance of 70 centimeters (25.5 inches), with no physical contact or radiation, and we have developed an automatic method that aims to detect breast cancer early, easily and as cheaply as possible.”
No more guesswork
“Physicians should be highly praised for their success rate in diagnosing breast cancer with the tools available today,” says Arnon, “but still, the death rate from breast cancer is unacceptable.”
Breast cancer is by far the most frequent cancer among women, with an estimated 1.38 million new cancer cases diagnosed in 2008 (accounting for 23 percent of all cancers), and is now the most common cancer both in developed and developing regions.
Though a medical doctor will oversee screenings with RUTH, “automatic” is one of its most key features. Results will not have to be interpreted by human eyes, thanks to the device’s unique process of calibration using mathematical algorithms formulated from three-dimensional models of hundreds of women with and without malignancies. The algorithms provide unprecedented accuracy, as Real Imaging has demonstrated in blind studies.
Op-Ed: Comparisons are odious
Agency sets an unhealthy precedent for ‘effectiveness’ research
By Trevor Butterworth Tuesday, May 29, 2012Imagine that all the pharmaceutical companies united to create an institute for quality research, and gave it $1 billion to study “comparative effectiveness” — whether drugs still under patent worked better for people than cheaper generics. Imagine that the pharma companies dug farther into their pockets and came up with another $11 million to train physicians, pharmacists and nurses to be ambassadors for this institute, and that these ambassadors would travel the country offering $4 million worth of further education credits to any doctors or nurses who would agree to listen to their spiel.
If you’re thinking that this is, in fact, what Big Pharma already does, remember, this is still a hypothetical exercise. In reality, such a plan would never get by the Food and Drug Administration, which is to drug marketing what the Spanish Inquisition was to heresy. But if, somehow, such a project were ever to happen, you’d seriously doubt whether it would be unbiased, wouldn’t you? It strains credibility to think that the pharmaceutical industry would go to such expense to say that the cheaper drugs were just as good as the expensive ones.
So guess what the U.S. government has gone and done? It’s given $1 billion to the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ) to study “comparative effectiveness.” And the agency, in turn, is paying a company — Total Therapeutic Management — $11.6 million to recruit and train doctors, pharmacists and nurses to shill the findings of these comparative-effectiveness studies at high-volume medical practices. As a reward for listening to the government’s spiel, you get a continuing education credit from a $4 million fund.
It’s not clear why the government is using taxpayer money to pay people to sit in a doctor’s office and explain the wonders to be found by going to AHRQ’s website (at present, not many). But in case these busy physicians miss out on this wonderful opportunity for no-cost, taxpayer-funded education, the government is spending another $26 million for a national and regional PR campaign to raise awareness about the program.
But here’s the really amazing thing about the government doing what pharmaceutical companies would be hung, drawn and quartered for doing: Because the government is doing this, it doesn’t need government oversight! Yes, the FDA, which normally polices what can and cannot be said in the promotion of health care, will have no jurisdiction at all over what this sales force will tell health care providers about how medicine should be practiced.
The immediate problem with this is simply the reverse of the problem dogging Big Pharma: If you’ve spent a billion dollars on a new drug, you have an interest in touting it as vastly better than the drug that preceded it. But if you have an interest in saving a billion dollars — and the U.S. government, as the world’s largest payer for health care, most certainly has such an interest — then surely you have a corresponding incentive to recommend cheaper treatments.
All of which leads to the multimillion-dollar, devil-in-the-details question: What does “comparative effectiveness” actually mean?
In theory, it means finding the best treatment for any given medical problem. But how are decisions made about what’s best? What if drug A cures 50 percent of people and costs $1 a pill and drug B cures 52 percent of people with the same problem but costs $10 a pill? The cost savings of, say, treating a million people each year on Medicare by using drug A are huge — but what if you happen to be in the 2 percent for whom only drug B works, and there’s no surefire way to figure that out before treatment?
The problem with comparative effectiveness (according to Peter Pitts, president of the Center for Medicine in the Public Interest and a former FDA associate commissioner) is that it’s very different from clinical effectiveness. The former aggregates health care outcomes for a given treatment, while the latter addresses variation within those outcomes — what works best and why, for the individual.
In a recent commentary in Drug Information Journal, Pitts warns that comparative effectiveness, as presently conceived, not only risks derailing the development of personalized medicine, it could end up pushing health care toward the slippery slope of rationing. There is always a trade-off between care and cost, but that trade-off keeps changing as medicine advances. What’s crazy expensive today could be far cheaper in five years’ time, and it could trigger further incremental breakthroughs in treatment.
A glance at the AHRQ’s link-heavy website shows that a lot of its reports are already old, while the billion dollars it got from Congress has yet to deliver any major new findings. This isn’t particularly surprising: Comparative effectiveness research takes time. But what if the eventual results end up being out of date — or get challenged as critically flawed? What will a government “comparative effectiveness” health rep say in such cases?
Again, we don’t know, because the government doesn’t think it needs to regulate itself as a provider of health care research and purchaser of health care. Even if you are an opponent of so-called socialized medicine, you, me and everyone else needs socialized regulation for promoting medicine and treatment. Government should play by the same rules it sets for others. In this case, our future depends on its doing so.
Get ready for many more such outrages: This is the agency that will determine which preventive services ObamaCare will require health plans to cover free of charge.
The task force claims that screening all adult men with the PSA (protein-specific antigen) test doesn’t prevent death from the disease. It argues that “the number of men who avoid dying of prostate cancer because of screening after 10 to 14 years is, at best, very small.”
Adding to the “costs” of the test are “false positives” — they tell people they have cancer when they don’t about 10 percent of the time. The task force thinks this problem makes the cost of screening higher than the tiny benefit screening generates for society.

First, the task force measures the effect of testing on the death rate from anydisease (all-cause mortality). That’s a bogus benchmark, because, as John Maynard Keynes famously noted, in the long run we all die. In fact, death rates from prostate cancer have dropped 57 percent among men ages 49 to 64 and80 percent among adult men over 75. National Cancer Institute data show that prostate cancers are being detected and treated earlier and that life expectancy is rising as a result.
The task force claims there is no evidence that screening directly reduces prostate cancer. But how, then, did death rates decline, if screening doesn’t work?
It does, of course. As prostate-cancer expert William Catalano notes, PSA screening is why the horror of not diagnosing this cancer until it has metastasized (advanced and spread) has all but disappeared.
The task force states that because the PSA test is imprecise, it will always lead to overdiagnosis. But false positives are a risk of all screening, and the error rate for prostate-cancer screening is no higher than screening for other illnesses or cancers.
Catalano also points out that it’s regular testing — not the test being used — that has likely contributed to raising the odds against the disease.
The task force also claims that the PSA test can’t tell us which tumors to treat. Yet it gives the patient and his doctorstime to figure that out.
For most patients, PSA screening gives a 5-to-10-year lead time — a vital window in which other new techniques (needle biopsies plus improvements in surgery and radiotherapy) can work.
Finally, the task force argues that PSA testing causes men to suffer from painful treatments and endure anxiety about false-positive results. It doesn’t measure this cost or have any data to support it. Worse, it disregards the scientific evidence that treatments reduce suffering and improve quality of life, even if they don’t always increase survival.
In reality, this ban is based on politics, not science. The task force — and similar ObamaCare agencies — applies standards that aren’t achievable. Going forward, new technologies would require decades of data and would have to demonstrate they’re nearly 100 perfect before ObamaCare would cover them.
Unless, of course, the procedure is politically popular: ObamaCare will treat contraception as cost-effective, although there’s no hard data to support that claim.
The value of health-care services, in other words, will be measured by political criteria, not by their ability to reduce suffering and death.
That’s an ugly future, indeed.